CJEU's new formulation of legal test to distinguish between anticompetitive agreements by object and by effect (C-345/14)

In its Judgment of 26 November 2015 in Maxima Latvija, C-345/14, EU:C:2015:784, the Court of Justice of the European Union (CJEU) has returned to the debate on the distinction between anticompetitive agreements by object and by effect for the purposes of the application of Art 101(1) TFEU [for background commentary of the case, see here].

This is a field of EU competition law of notable and growing complexity, fundamentally due to the lack of clear demarcating lines between both types of anticompetitive conduct [see S King, Agreements that restrict competition by object under Article 101(1) TFEU: past, present and future (2015) PhD Thesis, London School of Economics]. 

Some of the consequences of the distinction remain obscure or highly theoretical, not least because Art 101(1) TFEU covers both types of anticompetitive practices, which should therefore be subjected to similar sanctions (moderated only by the magnitude of the effects, where they exist). Two main areas of debate have emerged, though, around the (practical) boundaries where the categorisation carries legal weight: on the one hand, the possibility to exempt de minimis "by object" infringements; and, on the other hand, the standard of proof applicable to "by object" anticompetitive conduct.

Regarding the possibility to exempt de minimis "by object" infringements, the debate focuses on the implications of the CJEU Judgment of 13 December 2012 in Expedia (C-226/11, EU:C:2012:795), as well as the guidelines issued by the Commission in trying to clarify the state of the law [see the Guidance on restrictions of competition "by object" for the purpose of defining which agreements may benefit from the De Minimis Notice]. For the purposes of this discussion, it is worth stressing para 36, where the CJEU clarified that "the distinction between ‘infringements by object’ and ‘infringements by effect’ arises from the fact that certain forms of collusion between undertakings can be regarded, by their very nature, as being injurious to the proper functioning of normal competition" (emphasis added).

Regarding the standard of proof applicable to cases concerning "by object" anticompetitive conduct, the discussion revolves around the Judgment of 11 September 2014 in CB v Commission ('Cartes bancaires'; C-67/13 P, EU:C:2014:2204) [for discussion from a legal perspective, see here; and for an economic perspective, see here]. The significance of the Cartes bancaires Judgment is commonly seen as resting in the recasting of the case law in para 51, where the CJEU ruled that "it is established that certain collusive behaviour, such as that leading to horizontal price-fixing by cartels, may be considered so likely to have negative effects, in particular on the price, quantity or quality of the goods and services, that it may be considered redundant, for the purposes of applying Article [101(1) TFEU], to prove that they have actual effects on the market" (emphasis added).

In its Judgment in Maxima Latvija, the CJEU has followed the same general approach to the delineation between anticompetitive practices by object and by effect, and has consolidated the Cartes bancaires test. More specifically, the CJEU has ruled that
18 ... the concept of restriction of competition ‘by object’ ... must be interpreted restrictively and can be applied only to certain types of coordination between undertakings which reveal a sufficient degree of harm to competition that it may be found that there is no need to examine their effects ... That case-law arises from the fact that certain types of coordination between undertakings can be regarded, by their very nature, as being harmful to the proper functioning of normal competition ...
19 ... certain collusive behaviour, such as that leading to horizontal price-fixing by cartels, may be considered by their nature as likely to have negative effects, in particular on the price, quantity or quality of the goods and services, so that it may be considered redundant, for the purposes of applying Article 101(1) TFEU, to prove that they have actual effects on the market ... Experience shows that such behaviour leads to falls in production and price increases, resulting in poor allocation of resources to the detriment, in particular, of consumers.
20 ... the essential legal criterion for ascertaining whether an agreement involves a restriction of competition ‘by object’ is ... the finding that such an agreement reveals in itself a sufficient degree of harm to competition for it to be considered that it is not appropriate to assess its effects (C-345/14, paras 18-20, references omitted and emphasis added).
In my view, the formulation of this test is conceptually appealing. However, it is equally problematic because it relies on a test of 'balance of economic probabilities' that actually requires, in most cases, at least a quick look at the effects the anticompetitive practice has (or could have) generated. In terms of alleviating the burden of proof, this is less than clear cut. These complications are self-evident in the Maxima Latvija Judgment itself, where the CJEU applies this newly (re)formulated test as follows:
21 ... Maxima Latvija [an operator of large shops and hypermarkets] is not in a competitive situation with the shopping centres with which it has concluded the [lease] agreements at issue in the main proceedings. Although ... a fact of that nature in no way precludes an agreement from containing a restriction of competition ‘by object’ ... it must, however, be stated that the agreements at issue in the main proceedings are not among the agreements which it is accepted may be considered, by their very nature, to be harmful to the proper functioning of competition ...
22 Even if the clause at issue in the main proceedings could potentially have the effect of restricting the access of Maxima Latvija’s competitors to some shopping centres in which that company operates a large shop or hypermarket, such a fact, if established, does not imply clearly that the agreements containing that clause prevent, restrict or distort, by the very nature of the latter, competition on the relevant market, namely the local market for the retail food trade.
23 Taking account of the economic context in which agreements ... are to be applied, the analysis of the content of those agreements would not ... show, clearly, a degree of harm with regard to competition sufficient for those agreements to be considered to constitute a restriction of competition ‘by object’ within the meaning of Article 101(1) TFEU (C-345/14, paras 21-23, references omitted and emphasis added).
Looking at the application of the test in the Maxima Latvija case, two difficulties emerge. Firstly, there is no existing list of anticompetitive agreements by object (neither an open, closed or indicative list). This creates a significant complication and legal uncertainty, not least because of the potentially moving target of what constitutes "agreements which it is accepted may be considered, by their very nature, to be harmful to the proper functioning of competition".

Secondly, there is no clear indication as to what "degree of harm" (ie presumed anticompetitive effects) suffices to allow for an agreement to be categorised as "by object" rather than by effect. The need to consider the anticompetitive agreements in the "the economic context in which [those] agreements ... are to be applied" is a puzzling requirement from a legal perspective. If (one of) the main point(s) concerning the distinction between anticompetitive agreements "by object" and "by effect" is to clarify the burden of proof required for each of them (implicitly, in order to reduce the requirements for a finding of an anticompetitive agreement "by object"), then this requirement does not really help and ends up resulting in a slippery slope of relaxation of requirements depending on the general consensus (?) that some agreements are by their nature harmful.

Given the ongoing uncertainty, the test for the distinction between anticompetitive agreements by object and by effect is not likely to reduce litigation at all. Overall, then, this seems to be a never-ending discussion. In terms of legal simplicity, it could be preferable to return to a state of the law where it was clear that Art 101(1) TFEU covers both types of anticompetitive practices and triggers an enforcement procedure that needs to comply with the same requirements, regardless of whether ex post and in a specific case, it may look like some of the probatory efforts could have been spared. 

The classical justification for per se prohibitions and not rule of reason approaches is fundamentally based on enforcement costs--and that is, at least in part, why they are progressively abandoned in the US (see here). It seems clear to me that trying to create that distinction in this area is, unfortunately, not leading to any savings and, in that case, it may be worth avoiding a shaky per se rule...

'Winner' means WINNER and 'prize' means FREE PRIZE: The CJEU overshoots the mark of consumer protection (C-428/11)

In its Judgment of 18 October 2012 in case C-428/11 Purely Creative and Others v Office of Fair Trading, the CJEU was confronted with the interpretation of consumer protection rules in the field of aggressive commercial practices in a distant sales scenario. The CJEU has significantly raised the barrier for the conduct of commercial practices that include the award of 'prizes' and call the targeted consumer a 'winner' if she must assume any cost (even that of buying a stamp) to claim the prize, by determining that "the prohibition on making the consumer bear any cost whatsoever is absolute, whether it be the cost of a stamp or of a simple telephone conversation". In my opinion, the CJEU has overshot the mark of consumer protection.

In the case at hand, Purely Creative and other traders were sending individually addressed letters, scratch-cards and other advertising inserts placed into newspapers and magazines, by which the consumer was informed that he had won a prize or equivalent benefit, the value of which could be either considerable or merely symbolic. The consumer was offered a number of options in order to discover his prize and obtain a claim number: he could call a premium rate telephone number, use an SMS service or obtain the information by ordinary post (the latter method being given less prominent). The consumer was informed of the cost per minute and the maximum duration of the telephone call but was unaware that the company responsible for the promotion took a certain sum from the cost of the call (see curia press release here).

The Office of Fair Trading (OFT) took issue with these commercial practices and brought proceedings before the High Court of Justice of England and Wales, Chancery Division (Companies Court) seeking to restrain the traders from continuing to distribute promotions. The High Court found that the promotions involved unfair practices, albeit on a more limited basis than contended by the OFT. In short, the High Court found that the commercial practices would only be acceptable "if the payment required was de minimis (such as the purchase of a stamp or the cost of an ordinary telephone call), no part of which would benefit the trader concerned, and if that payment were de minimis compared with the value of the prize won" (account rendered by the CJEU in C-428/11 at para 19, emphasis added).


Therefore, the High Court passed undertakings by which traders committed not to ‘create the false impression that the consumer has already won, will win or will on doing a particular act win, a prize or equivalent benefit, when in fact taking any action recommended by the [trader] in relation to claiming the prize or other equivalent benefit is subject to the consumer paying money or incurring a cost which is either: (a) a substantial proportion of the unit cost to the defendant of the provision to the consumer of the thing described as a prize or other equivalent benefit; or (b) in the case of a charge stated to be for delivery and insurance, used by the defendant to finance in whole or in part its acquisition, handling or other cost of the making available of that thing, other than the actual cost of its delivery to the consumer and insurance (if any) in transit’  (account rendered by the CJEU in C-428/11 at para 20, emphasis added).

Traders appealed and the OFT cross-appealed the High Court ruling before the Court of Appeal (England and Wales) (Civil Division), which referred the case to the CJEU for a preliminary ruling whereby it seeked an interpretation of paragraph 31 of Annex I to the Directive 2005/29/EC of the European Parliament and of the Council of 11 May 2005 concerning unfair business-to-consumer commercial practices in the internal market (OJ 2005 L 149, p. 22) in order to determine whether that provision prohibits the imposition of a cost, even of a de minimis nature, on a consumer who has been informed that they have won a prize.

According to the CJEU, indeed, the proper legal basis for the analysis in this case was Dir 2005/29/EC and, more specifically, its rules preventing the conduct of aggressive commercial practices against consumers. According to Art 8 Dir 2005/29/EC, 'A commercial practice shall be regarded as aggressive if, in its factual context, taking account of all its features and circumstances, by harassment, coercion, including the use of physical force, or undue influence, it significantly impairs or is likely to significantly impair the average consumer’s freedom of choice or conduct with regard to the product and thereby causes him or is likely to cause him to take a transactional decision that he would not have taken otherwise'.

More specifically, annex I to the Dir 2005/29/EC is a list of 31 paragraphs that describe practices which are in all circumstances regarded as unfair. Under paragraph 20, ‘[d]escribing a product as “gratis”, “free”, “without charge” or similar if the consumer has to pay anything other than the unavoidable cost of responding to the commercial practice and collecting or paying for delivery of the item’ is considered an unfairly aggressive commercial practice. Identically, under paragraph 31, ‘[c]reating the false impression that the consumer has already won, will win, or will on doing a particular act win, a prize or other equivalent benefit, when in fact either, [a)] there is no prize or other equivalent benefit, or [b)] taking any action in relation to claiming the prize or other equivalent benefit is subject to the consumer paying money or incurring a cost.’

In Purely Creative v OFT, the CJEU has adopted a very strict, absolute interpretation of paragraph 31 of annex I of Dir 2005/29/EC by finding that:
29 [...] the term ‘false’ is not vital to an understanding of paragraph 31 of Annex I to the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive but merely reinforces the sentence in question (sic). The prohibited practice consists in the creation of one of the impressions referred to in the first part of that paragraph, whereas, as stated in the second part of that paragraph, those impressions do not correspond to reality.
30 [...] according to the wording of that provision, an unfair practice exists where the consumer is subject to a requirement to pay money or incur a cost on taking any action to claim what is presented to him as a prize or other equivalent benefit. That wording does not allow for any exception, meaning that it is evident that the expression ‘incur a cost’ does not allow the consumer to bear the slightest cost, even if it is de minimis compared with the value of the prize or a cost which would not procure any advantage for the trader, such as the cost of a stamp.
31 The wording of the phrase ‘action in relation to claiming the prize’ is imprecise, it being possible therefore that it covers, inter alia, any step taken by the consumer in order to obtain information about the nature of his prize or to collect it. [...]
34 In addition, given the absolute nature of the prohibition on imposing any cost, the offer of a number of options cannot eliminate the unfair character of the practice if any of the proposed options were to require the consumer to bear a cost, even a de minimis cost compared with the value of the prize. [...]
38 [...] the practice at issue in paragraph 31, second indent, of Annex I to the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive exploits the psychological effect caused by the announcement of the winning of a prize, in order to induce the consumer to make a choice which is not always rational, such as calling a premium rate telephone number to ask for information about the nature of the prize, travelling at great expense to collect an item of low-value crockery or paying the delivery costs of a book which he already has (sic). [...]
40 [...] prohibiting traders from making the consumer bear the slightest cost would not make it impossible to organise such promotional campaigns. The trader could impose a geographic limitation on participation in the competition or in the promotion, so as to limit the costs he would have to bear which are associated with travel by the consumer and with the formalities for the consumer’s taking possession of the prize. When determining the value of the prizes to be distributed, the trader could also take into account the communication or delivery costs he would have to bear. [...]
42 [...] clarification of the interpretation of paragraph 31 of Annex I to the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive can be provided by a reading of paragraph 20 of that annex. According to that provision, there is a misleading practice where a product is described as ‘gratis’, ‘free’ ‘without charge’ or similar if the consumer has to pay anything other than the unavoidable cost of responding to the commercial practice and collecting or paying for delivery of the item. Paragraph 31 of Annex I to the directive does not contain similar wording, confirming that that paragraph should be interpreted as meaning that the prohibition on making the consumer bear any cost whatsoever is absolute, whether it be the cost of a stamp or of a simple telephone conversation (sic). [...]
49 It is, therefore, in order to protect the consumer that the concept of a true ‘prize’ should be preserved, by interpreting paragraph 31 of Annex I to that directive as meaning that a prize in respect of which the consumer is obliged to make a payment of whatever kind cannot be regarded as a ‘prize’.
50 [...] it is not permissible to allow action to be taken in relation to the claiming of a prize pursuant to a multi-option scheme, proposed to the consumer by the trader, where at least one of the methods would not involve any payment. It is the very prospect of taking possession of the prize which influences the consumer and may cause him to take a decision he would not take otherwise, such as choosing the quickest method of finding out what prize he has won, even though that may be the most expensive method. (C-428/11 at paras 29 to 50, emphasis added).
In a nutshell, the position of the CJEU makes life very difficult for companies willing to attract consumers by offering legitimate and true prizes, since they now have to internalize the tiniest of the costs involved. This position is very strict and, from my view, overshoots the mark--possibly on the basis of rather extreme assumptions of irrational consumer behaviour such as those presented in paragraph 38 of the Judgment (which, in my view, do not seem to represent the actual behaviour of the average consumer or would, at least, have deserved some further evidentiary support). The position advanced by the High Court of Justice of England and Wales, Chancery Division (Companies Court) was preferable because it set a more proportionate standard. I find two faults in the reasoning of the CJEU.

First, in paragraph 29, I think that the CJEU fails to give proper value to the expression 'false' impression. If the consumer is not mislead because she has full, proper information of the de minimis costs required to claim the prize, there seems to be no need to extend the protection. In this regard, resorting to paragraph 20 as an interpretative tool seems correct, but the CJEU seems to have extracted the wrong conclusions. Given that paragraph 20 deals with the concept of 'free' (a rather absolute and appealing concept) and still allows for de minimis charges that are the unavoidable cost of responding to the commercial practice, it seems to impose a clear de minimis threshold for the analysis of the relevance of the costs retained by consumers (ie not internalized by the trader running the promotion). And this de minimis threshold or safe harbour should have been extended to paragraph 31 under the systematic interpretation conducted by the CJEU. Otherwise, the construction of paragraph 31 of annex I Dir 2005/29/EC as the CJEU at para 42 of Purely Creative v OFT is an expansive interpretation of a prohibitive rule (since the 'absolute' element of no-cost that the CJEU brings to the provision is arguably not there, once resort to paragrah 20 is had as an interpretative tool). And expansive or analogic interpretation of prohibitive rules runs against basic principles of legal interpretation [whatever is not prohibited is thereby ipso facto permitted].

Second, the reasoning that the CJEU offers to support the adoption of such a per se prohibition seems faulty too. At paras 45 to 47 of Purely Creative v OFT he CJEU considers that
45 As is apparent from the recitals in the preamble to the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive, in particular recital 17, legal certainty is an essential element for the sound functioning of the internal market. It was in order to attain that objective that the legislature collected in Annex I to the directive the commercial practices which are, in all circumstances, unfair and which, therefore, do not require a case-by-case assessment against the provisions of Articles 5 to 9 of that directive.
46 That objective would not be achieved if paragraph 31 of Annex I to the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive were interpreted as including an element of misleading conduct, distinct from the situations described in the second part of that provision. Difficult assessments would have to be carried out, on a case-by-case basis, in order to prove that element, which is precisely what Annex I to the directive sought to avoid by including that practice.
47 Equally, that objective would not be achieved if traders were allowed to impose on the consumer costs which are ‘de minimis’ compared with the value of the prize. That would make it necessary to determine evaluation methods both for the costs and the prizes and would also require such evaluations to be carried out (C-428/11 at paras 45 to 47, emphasis added).
Formally, the reasoning is correct. However, it is in open contradiction with the following finding of the CJEU in the same Judgment: "[c]lear and sufficient consumer information is important where the trader wishes to ensure that consumers can identify a prize and assess its nature" (para 53) and, therefore "[l]ike every other item of information provided by a trader to a consumer, information on the substance of the prize must be examined and assessed by the national courts in the light of recitals 18 and 19 in the preamble to the {Dir 2005/29/EC], and of Article 5(2)(b) of the directive. That concerns the availability of the information and how it is presented, the legibility and clarity of the wording and whether it can be understood by the public targeted by the practice" (para 55). Therefore, national courts cannot conduct an automatic interpretation of paragraph 31 of annex I of Dir 2005/29/EC anyway. And, if so, the provision is simply badly tailored to become a per se rule--which should allow for a case by case scrutiny of the information provided to consumers (ie the 'false impression' prong of the text) as well as of the actual costs necessary to redeem the prize (as ruled by the High Court of England and Wales). Otherwise, we have an asymmetrical per se rule that unnecessarily restricts business possibilities without clearly increasing (actual, effective) consumer protection, nor reducing litigation (costs and occurrences).

Therefore, in my opinion, the CJEU has overshot the mark by adopting such an absolute interpretation of paragraph 31 of annex I of Dir 2005/29/EC.